Leadership & People
Opinion Article
INVITED EDITOR
Editorial from
Rita Alexandra Gouveia da Silva
Nova SBE alumna, currently exploring the HR world at Unbel.
July 16, 2024
4. Quality education

4. Quality education

Ensure access to inclusive, quality and equitable education and promote lifelong learning opportunities for all.
LEARN MORE

The effects of overconfidence in job market signaling — an experimental approach

Education can work as a signal that workers send to employers to indicate their productivity. Since a worker’s productivity can only be observed after the employer has already hired him, they must rely on signs to predict which salary will be the most appropriate for a worker.

It is important to understand how markets work with asymmetric information because, in reality, it’s very common that one side of a market has more information than another. One of the classic asymmetric information problems studied in economics is the Spence signaling model, Spence (1973). In this paper, Spence described a stylized example of workers with private information about their ability or productivity, trying to signal their productivity to firms who compete to hire them. Education can work as a signal that workers send to employers to indicate their productivity. Since a worker’s productivity can only be observed after the employer has already hired him, they must rely on those signs to predict which salary will be the most appropriate for a worker. For the signaling model to work, there has to be a negative relationship between the marginal productivity of the worker and the cost of sending the signal. In the context of education, it means that the less productive a worker is, the more costly it will be for that person to obtain an education. This should ensure that highly productive workers get more education than low productivity workers and that low productivity workers do not find it profitable to imitate high productivity workers.

Since there is not very much evidence about the signaling model, and evidence from behavioral and experimental economics suggests that people don’t always behave according to theory, I believe it is worth reflecting on how people evaluate their own abilities. If they, in fact, misevaluate them, this can lead to biases such as overconfidence. In the case of the signaling model, this means that some workers may believe they are high types, when in fact they are low types. This leads us to the following questions: Are all low productive workers aware of their limitations? Do firms also perceive that workers can be overconfident? How does this affect the equilibrium?

To find an answer to these questions, I conducted two online surveys: one from the employers’ perspective and one from the workers’ perspective. In both surveys, the setup is the same, in which two firms are competing to hire one worker. The employers’ survey asks questions regarding the wage choice given the signal. The workers’ survey asks questions regarding the choice of sending, or not, the signal, depending on different wages.

I observed that there are relevant differences between firms’ wage offers and the workers’ predictions. On average, workers are expecting a wage for workers who don’t send the signal 11 % lower than what firms decide to offer them. On the other hand, they expect a wage 53 % higher for workers who send the signal, comparing to firms’ real offers. This discrepancy between prediction and reality can be the cause for people to make uninformed decisions regarding, in this case, investments in education.

One of the main objectives was also to compare firms’ beliefs about the workers with the actual ratio between high and low productivity workers. I saw that there were a lot more high productivity workers not sending the signal and more low productivity workers sending the signal than theory predicted, which indicates not only an overconfidence bias but also an under-confidence bias. It seems that employers acknowledged the possibility of overconfidence, but in an excessive way: in reality, there were less low productivity workers sending the signal than the employers predicted.

In the end, the most relevant consequences are to be observed in the profits. Profits were significantly lower when subjects “misbehaved,” with high productivity workers losing an average of 22 % and low productivity workers losing an astonishing 240 % of profits. These results really show the negative effects of overconfidence on workers. For high productivity workers, the average wages offered were made smaller to account for low productivity workers sending the signal, and for low productivity workers, the average wages offered didn’t compensate for their miscalculated costs in investing in the signal. Firms lost an average of 187% of profit for hiring both types of workers.

Takeaways from these observations might seem a little too harsh: people with fewer capabilities shouldn’t invest so much in education, and firms should be more cautious with how they assess people’s productivity before hiring. However, there’s one very interesting assumption that is made theoretically for which real-world applicability can be questioned. The model we just explored assumes that education works only as a signal, not having any real contribution to more productivity. One can very easily argue that people who get more education actually gain capabilities, which makes for the case that people’s types, non-productive and productive, aren’t intrinsic to them after all, but instead altered by the education they get.

No matter what the beliefs are regarding if types can be altered through education or not, it’s always important that people know themselves so they can invest wisely and predict their outcomes as best as possible. From the firms’ perspective, the solution includes a stricter, more challenging recruitment process, and safety net-clauses like probation periods

Rita Alexandra Gouveia da Silva
Nova SBE alumna, currently exploring the HR world at Unbel.
LEARN MORE
SHARE

Keep reading

Let's discuss students' evaluation?

In the last two years, because of the covid-19 pandemic, national exams did not count towards the conclusion of secondary subjects but only towards access to higher education. Does it make sense for this to become the rule from now on? The topic is analyzed and discussed in this episode of Zona de Impacto by researchers and students from Nova SBE Catarina Ângelo and Pedro Freitas, and Professor Ana Balcão Reis.

Interview with Salvador Mendes de Almeida

Nova SBE Professor, journalist and author, Laurinda Alves interviews Salvador Mendes de Almeida, founder of Associação Salvador, to get to know his impactful story. In this inspiring conversation, we understand how did Salvador find his Role to Play towards building a more inclusive society for all and continues to regardless of the challenges caused by the pandemic.

Zona de Impacto: Mentalities evolved; however, women are still discriminated in the job market. Why?

Statistics are known. Women have a higher qualification rate than men, but they receive less (for the same jobs) and are more precarious. When it is time to reach roles of responsibility, they have a harder life (and, as the companies get bigger, the worse it is). The topic is old, solutions take a long time to produce effects, and this worries the youth. Marta Everard and Rita Mendes, students at NovaSBE and members of the club Women on Board, explain how they perceive their labor’s future

The effects of overconfidence in job market signaling — an experimental approach

Education can work as a signal that workers send to employers to indicate their productivity. Since a worker’s productivity can only be observed after the employer has already hired him, they must rely on signs to predict which salary will be the most appropriate for a worker.

THE CHOICES OF

Nova SBE awarded at the 1st edition of the EFFAS Gasperini Awards

Professors Miguel Ferreira and José Tavares and Nova SBE PhD student Sharmin Sazedj were awarded the first edition of the EFFAS Gasperini Awards, where they represented Nova SBE

Subscribe our weekly newsletter

By subscribing to the Nova SBE Role to Play newsletter, you can stay up-to-date on the latest articles posted on the website.
Thank you! Your submission has been received!
Oops! Something went wrong while submitting the form.

We all have a role to play

We are on a mission to be a community dedicated to the development of talent and knowledge that impacts the world.

With just ten years to go, an ambitious global effort is underway to deliver the 2030 promise. We want to take a stand and we are calling on our community to showcase how they are contributing to the 17 Sustainable Development Goals, whilst influencing more and more people to unravel their role to play.

Here, you will find four different ways your ideas can flourish, dialogue can be enhanced, and action can take place. You can choose one or all four, and Nova SBE will be there to support you all the way and guarantee tangible change.

We all have a role to play, and this is your way in.